The central premise of Globalization and its Discontents
is straightforward: pro-globalization policies can yield substantial benefits
if implemented judiciously, with due consideration for the unique
characteristics of each country. Countries should embrace globalization on
their own terms, accounting for their individual history, culture, and
traditions. However, poorly designed or universally applied pro-globalization
policies can be detrimental, leading to increased instability, heightened
vulnerability to external shocks, reduced growth, and elevated poverty.
Stiglitz contends that the problem lies in the hasty and
inequitable implementation of globalization. Liberalization policies have been
introduced too quickly, in an incorrect sequence, and often based on inadequate
or flawed economic analyses. Consequently, he argues, we are now witnessing
dire consequences, including rising destitution, social conflict, and
widespread frustration. Stiglitz places the blame on the IMF, its "market
fundamentalists," the "Washington Consensus," and the US
Treasury.
According to Stiglitz, in the early 1990s, the IMF, World
Bank, and the US Treasury collaborated in what he sees as a kind of global
economic reform conspiracy—the infamous "Washington Consensus."
However, this perspective oversimplifies the situation and overlooks the
evolution of reform thinking over the last two decades. In the 1980s and early
1990s, policymakers in many developing nations were often more progressive than
the multilaterals or the Treasury. Countries like Argentina, Chile, and Mexico,
for instance, implemented reforms based on a "national consensus"
that was more imaginative and far-reaching than what Washington bureaucrats
were willing to accept at the time. The IMF initially criticized Chile's social
security reform, opposed Argentina's currency board, and was skeptical of
Mexico's trade-opening strategy during the mid-1980s. Stiglitz contends that
the emphasis on how to undertake economic reform originated from a group of
developing countries' economists, particularly from Latin America, rather than
from the multilaterals.
Stiglitz's critique of globalization focuses on three
interconnected policy issues: (1) Ignoring crucial aspects of the sequencing
and pace of reform during the 1990s, leading to overly fast and improperly
ordered implementations. Stiglitz favors a gradualist approach. (2) The
significant mistake of advocating and imposing capital account liberalization.
(3) The IMF's response to crises, particularly the East Asian crisis, which he
deems a disaster that exacerbated problems. Imposing fiscal austerity and
raising interest rates, according to Stiglitz, were detrimental mistakes that
cost East Asian countries several points in terms of growth. Consistent with
his theoretical writings over the past 35 years, Stiglitz frames his criticism
around the insights of the theory of asymmetric information.
Stiglitz argues that a different approach, specifically
his own, could have led to significantly better social outcomes. While I found
his arguments persuasive at times, there were instances where I questioned the
seriousness of his proposals. For instance, I was skeptical when reading his
suggestion, on pages 129 and 231, that the 2002 Argentine crisis could have
been averted by adopting a more expansive fiscal policy.
Stiglitz consistently emphasizes the crucial role of
speed and sequencing in implementing economic liberalization successfully.
While this principle is undeniably important, it is not novel in policy
discussions. Adam Smith, in "The Wealth of Nations," recognized the
difficulty of determining the appropriate sequencing, attributing it primarily
to political considerations. He advocated for gradualism, much like Stiglitz,
based on the belief that abrupt liberalization would lead to a significant
increase in unemployment.
In the early 1980s, the World Bank extensively explored
issues related to sequencing and the speed of reform. A consensus emerged on
key principles: gradual trade liberalization supported by substantial foreign
aid, efforts to minimize unemployment consequences, early management of fiscal
imbalances in high-inflation countries, establishment of modern supervisory and
regulatory agencies for financial reform, and liberalization of the capital
account at the end of the process.
However, during the early 1990s, this consensus on
sequencing and speed was challenged, with calls for simultaneous and rapid
reforms gaining traction in Washington. Advocates argued that this approach was
necessary politically to overcome opposition to liberalization efforts. Stiglitz
critiques this "rapid and simultaneous" reform strategy, particularly
exemplified by Vaclav Klaus. Yet, his criticism fails to address the political
economy concerns that motivated Klaus and other reformers in Central and
Eastern Europe at the time.
In 1992, responding to perceived US pressure on capital
account liberalization, a conference organized by Yung Chul Park highlighted
broad support for appropriate sequencing and the risks of premature capital
account opening. Participants, including Robert Mundell, recognized negative
externalities, such as borrowing for consumption rather than investment,
potentially leading to unsustainable debt burdens.
Stiglitz's contention that a more deliberate approach
could have yielded better outcomes echoes longstanding discussions in economic
thought, emphasizing the importance of political, economic, and social context
in reform implementation.
At the 1992 Seoul conference on capital liberalization,
Manuel Guitian, a senior IMF official, was among the few dissenters favoring a
swift move toward capital account convertibility. In contrast to Stiglitz's
characterization of IMF leadership, Guitian's stance lacked dogma or arrogance.
Guitian's paper, titled "Capital Account Liberalization: Bringing Policy
in Line with Reality," documented the IMF's evolving views on sequencing
and capital account convertibility. Guitian argued that there was no a priori
reason to delay simultaneous opening of current and capital accounts.
From 1995, several countries started relaxing capital
controls, but they adopted different strategies. Some focused on relaxing bank
lending, others permitted only long-term capital movements, and countries like
Chile employed market-based mechanisms to control capital inflows. Many
countries, however, opened their capital accounts without external pressure.
Indonesia and Mexico, for instance, had a longstanding tradition of free
capital mobility.
While Stiglitz acknowledges the importance of sequencing,
he does not delve into the nuanced and challenging issue of how and when to
remove capital controls. Recent research suggests that, in certain
circumstances, a freer capital account positively affects long-term growth.
Transparent mechanisms, like Chile's flexible tax on short-term inflows, are
considered effective transitional devices, but even these have associated
costs.
Stiglitz critiques the IMF's handling of the East Asian
crisis, citing major mistakes such as closing banks during a financial panic,
bailing out private and foreign creditors, opposing capital controls on
outflows, and enforcing tight fiscal policies and high-interest rates. Stiglitz
argues that China and India's experiences, along with Malaysia's quick recovery
without following IMF advice, support his views. However, these arguments are
deemed unpersuasive due to oversimplification and failure to account for
multiple factors influencing crisis outcomes.
Stiglitz's criticisms regarding the IMF's fiscal and
interest rate policies during the East Asian crisis are severe but lack
empirical support. He contends that the IMF's insistence on contractionary
fiscal policies exacerbated the recession and that mandated interest rate
increases led to bankruptcies, deepening the confidence crisis. However, these
arguments are challenged as the situation in late 1997 constituted major
currency crises, not just severe downturns, necessitating a different policy
approach to address declining demand for government securities and domestic
money.
In the midst of a major currency crisis, the primary
imperative is to restore confidence. Recurrent bankruptcies, substantial
deficits translated into money printing, and rapidly depreciating exchange
rates are all factors that fail to contribute positively to achieving this
goal. However, a delicate balance must be struck, as large deficits converted
into money printing and allowing the exchange rate to depreciate excessively
may not be conducive to re-establishing confidence.
Ultimately, the decision revolves around trade-offs,
specifically how much to permit the exchange rate to depreciate and to what
extent, and for how long, interest rates should be increased. The government's
objectives play a crucial role in determining the course of action. If the
authorities aim to prevent default and runaway inflation, as is typically the
case for East Asian governments, allowing the exchange rate to spiral out of
control poses significant risks. In most situations, injecting liquidity when
the demand for money is dwindling and issuing government debt when there is a mass
sell-off of government securities may not be effective in restoring confidence
or preventing an inflationary crisis.
No comments:
Post a Comment