The essence of David Harvey's
book lies in its exploration of the limits, contradictions, crisis tendencies,
and irrationality inherent within capitalism. Grounded in a meticulous analysis
of Marx's writings, Harvey's mastery of the original texts is commendable,
offering readers a profound understanding of Marx's arguments. Harvey's writing
is clear and engaging, effectively conveying his views while navigating through
conflicting interpretations of Marx's work. He fearlessly critiques Marx's
analyses where he perceives shortcomings, thus initiating an inquiry into the
boundaries of Marxian thought.
The initial seven chapters of
the book constitute a meticulous examination of Marx's theory, culminating in
what Harvey describes as a "first cut" theory of capitalist crisis
rooted in the contradictory nature of capitalist production, particularly
influenced by Marx's notion of the falling rate of profit. Harvey skillfully
addresses various critiques of Marx, illustrating the depth and nuance of
Marx's work and refuting claims of technological determinism by emphasizing the
social dimensions of Marx's analysis. However, Harvey is not merely a blind
adherent to Marx; he adeptly critiques Marx's own limitations, notably
regarding the transformation problem and the concept of the falling rate of
profit. Harvey resolves some of these issues, particularly by reconciling the
differing notions of accumulation presented in different volumes of Capital. He
argues that the credit system serves as a mechanism to standardize turnover
times of capital, with the rate of interest acting as a common basis.
Chapter One sets the stage by
delving into the foundational concepts of Marxian analysis, with a particular
emphasis on the labor theory of value, class relations, and principles of
accumulation central to capitalism. Harvey adeptly elucidates these concepts,
steering clear of the intricate debates often found in Marxist literature, such
as the transformation problem. Throughout the book, the issue of value remains
prominent, informing various aspects of Harvey's examination.
Chapter Two shifts focus to
the structure of production and distribution, particularly highlighting the
nature of wage labor. Subsequently, the consumption sphere takes center stage
in Chapter Three, where Harvey endeavors to integrate Keynesian and Kaleckian
theories with Marxian analysis, albeit with some divergence in thought.
Chapters Four and Five delve
into the dynamics of technological change, the labor process, and the
organization of capitalist production. Harvey contends that technology is not
an autonomous force but rather a tool shaped by class relations to sustain
labor productivity and drive capital accumulation. He elucidates how
technological advancements reflect and perpetuate class antagonisms, ultimately
leading to the domination of labor in service of capital accumulation.
By the end of Chapter Four,
Harvey lays the groundwork for a Marxian theory of the capitalist labor
process, emphasizing the pervasive influence of class domination throughout
production. He highlights the de-skilling of labor and the intensification of
exploitation as manifestations of capitalism's imperative for accumulation.
Chapter Five of the book
stands out as an exemplary exploration of the inherent tensions within
capitalism, particularly regarding its structuring around principles of market
decentralization. David Harvey adeptly captures the ongoing struggle between
decentralization and centralization within the capitalist framework, going
beyond the surface-level behaviors of individual enterprises to unveil the
conscious design underlying capitalism's organization. In doing so, Harvey's
analysis aligns with contemporary efforts, such as those by Piore and others,
to comprehend the formal organization of alternative market exchange regimes.
Harvey portrays capitalism not
as a natural or inevitable phenomenon but rather as a deliberately crafted
system governed by rules and procedures. Throughout the book, his aim is to
unravel the tensions and contradictions inherent in capitalism, a task
formalized in Chapters Six and Seven, which focus on accumulation,
reproduction, and crisis. Here, labor's relationship with capital and the
overarching structure of capitalism take center stage, revealing how the
seemingly rational behavior of individual capitalists can pose existential
threats to the entire system.
Harvey's "first-cut"
theory of crisis revolves around the falling rate of profit, over-accumulation,
and the devaluation of capital.
Harvey suggests that the focus
on the falling rate of profit somewhat obscures the fundamental insight of
Capital: the perpetual disequilibrium between productive forces and social
relations under capitalism. By the end of the initial section, readers are
treated to a clear and insightful introduction to Marxist theory, characterized
by Harvey's constructive and candid approach.
In the subsequent chapters,
Harvey endeavors to extend Marx's analysis into unfamiliar territories. He
explores mechanisms that temporarily suppress the inherent tendency towards
overaccumulation, such as the development of new circulatory forms and credit
regulation, leading to what he terms a "second-cut" theory of
capitalist crisis by chapter 10. This theory builds upon the initial framework rather
than replacing it, emphasizing the moderating role of credit systems in
mitigating the destabilizing effects of capitalist competition.
Harvey's second-cut crisis
theory posits that while credit systems moderate crises stemming from unbridled
competition, they introduce a new set of contradictions, particularly
manifested in the antagonism between the financial system and its monetary
base. The persistence of overaccumulation, fueled by the proliferation of
"fictitious capital," tends to precipitate speculative bubbles and
financial crises, necessitating increased state intervention. Consequently,
crises transform from purely economic phenomena into political crises, as state
involvement becomes crucial in managing financial instability.
The final three chapters of
the book shift focus back to the built environment, introducing geography as a
key element in Harvey's "third-cut" theory of crisis. This
integration hinges on a particular conception of space, emphasizing its dynamic
and context-dependent nature. Harvey's analysis foregrounds location as a
central consideration, yet it remains deeply interconnected with previous
discussions. For instance, his examination of capitalism's organization offers
insights into the spatial arrangement of the economic system, while his
analysis of the labor process lays the groundwork for exploring spatial
divisions of labor. Throughout these chapters, Harvey's adept synthesis of
economic and geographical perspectives enriches our understanding of
capitalism's complexities and sheds light on the intricate interplay between
space and socioeconomic dynamics.
Harvey expresses hope that the
theoretical discussions presented within the text will not only enhance the
study of history but also inform the formulation of political practices.
Indeed, the book offers valuable insights that can be applied across various
domains, as evidenced by the critical examination of capitalist production and
its impact on housing, land speculation, and urban planning.
Harvey challenges conventional
economic perspectives by shedding light on the inherent contradictions within
capitalist housing relations. He argues that phenomena like land speculation
and property boom-and-bust cycles are not aberrations but rather integral
components of capitalist social relations. By contextualizing these dynamics
within the broader framework of capitalist accumulation, Harvey provides a
nuanced understanding of the interconnectedness between spatial configurations,
financial speculation, and crisis formation.
Moreover, Harvey's analysis
extends beyond housing to encompass broader discussions on differential rent,
government intervention, and the evolving nature of capitalist institutions. He
underscores the continuous transformation inherent in capitalist processes,
cautioning against oversimplified comparisons that fail to capture the dynamic
nature of social change.
One of the book's major
achievements is its exploration of the contradictory unity of time and space in
capitalist society. Harvey demonstrates how capitalist accumulation redefines
temporal and geographical horizons, leading to both order and chaos. By
highlighting the dialectical relationship between spatial organization and
disorganization, Harvey emphasizes the centrality of space to social analysis
while acknowledging its complex interplay with temporal dynamics.
Throughout his work, David
Harvey presents Marx's ideas with a commanding authority, aiming to offer what
he perceives as the most developed interpretation compared to previous attempts.
However, there are some potential shortcomings in Harvey's approach that
warrant consideration.
Firstly, Harvey's pursuit of a
"correct" interpretation may inadvertently lead to a form of
"originalism," wherein he seeks to uphold a definitive interpretation
where none may truly exist. Interpretation, by its nature, is subjective and
normative, shaped by evolving contexts and perspectives. While Harvey admirably
navigates Marx's texts with depth and insight, it's essential to recognize the
inherent limitations of attempting to pin down a single authoritative
interpretation.
Secondly, Harvey's analysis of
the state within capitalism appears somewhat conventional, emphasizing its
functional role in ensuring the reproduction of capitalist relations. While he
acknowledges the state's significance, his treatment may overlook its relative
autonomy and the complexities of its actions beyond merely serving capitalist
interests. This limited perspective on the state could benefit from further
exploration to better understand its multifaceted role in society.
Thirdly, Harvey's treatment of
time and space may be overly abstract, lacking sufficient integration of
Marxist and Keynesian perspectives on economic cycles. By compartmentalizing
short-run and long-run dynamics, Harvey risks overlooking the
interconnectedness and fluidity of economic processes over time. Additionally,
his conceptualization of space as primarily functional rather than inherently
dynamic or relational may overlook its broader significance in shaping social
and economic relations.
No comments:
Post a Comment